Articles - What option prices reveal about future financial risk


Insurance companies are experts at using historical data to form views on possible future outcomes. These views are then used in a variety of ways from setting assumptions for calculating technical provisions and calibrating internal models, to assessing risk exposures and designing and evaluating hedging strategies. But what if there was a way to peer into the future rather than just the past? Option prices in financial markets can provide exactly that: forward-looking insights into probability distributions for financial risks.

 By Amit Lad, Principal, Insurance and Longevity Consulting, Barnett Waddingham

 This article explores how insurers can leverage the insights embedded in option prices to help validate their forward-looking risk estimates and obtain real-time indicators of potential changes in risk outlooks.

 The limitations of the rear-view mirror
 Traditional risk calibrations typically analyse long-term historical data, implicitly assuming that past patterns will continue into the future. Our economic and financial world is probably highly non-stationary, and there is little reason to be confident that long-term historical observations are outcomes of the same probabilistic processes that will drive the outcomes of tomorrow (think Knightian risk and uncertainty). And even if we are in a world of well-behaved and well-understood risk, financial risks rarely have a long enough period of credible historical data available to robustly support risk calibrations at the one-in-200 year tail that is often of greatest interest to actuaries and capital models. Consequently, the standard errors of tail percentile estimates will often be uncomfortably large.

 Option prices can offer a complementary perspective by revealing how market participants are currently pricing forward-looking risks. This provides a ‘point-in-time’ (PIT) perspective that is at odds with the typical ‘through-the-cycle’ (TTC) interpretation of internal model calibrations. Nonetheless, by monitoring changes in the PIT view, and its divergence from the TTC view, it can provide useful insights for supporting calibrations, and supporting risk management more generally.

 A simple example: 99.5% one-year VaR on the FTSE100
 Let’s take the FTSE100 index as an example and start with a single option price: a one-year at-the-money call option price. As at end-June 2025, the volatility implied by the Black-Scholes model by this option price was approximately 14%.

 Using this as our best estimate of one-year FTSE100 index volatility and assuming a lognormal distribution with an equity risk premium of 4%, we can calculate that the 99.5th percentile one-year change in the equity index would be a fall of c27%1.

 This quick calculation gives us a starting point, but it relies on a significant assumption: that equity returns follow a lognormal distribution and have constant volatility as assumed in the Black-Scholes model.

 Enriching our view: the volatility smile
 At any given term to maturity, we can often find options traded with a range of different strike prices. When we examine how option prices vary with strike prices, we observe something interesting – implied volatilities aren't constant across different strikes. This phenomenon, known as the 'volatility smile' or 'skew', contradicts the Black-Scholes assumption of constant volatility.

 For example, the chart below shows the implied volatilities of a range of one-year FTSE 100 call options with a range of different strike prices.

 

 This volatility smile suggests that the market does not believe the FTSE100’s one-year probability distribution is a lognormal distribution as per our introductory example.

 For the FTSE100, options with lower strike prices (in-the-money call or out-the-money puts) have higher implied volatilities than at-the-money options. This pattern implies the market attaches higher probabilities to significant downside moves. The 99.5th percentile index fall implied by these prices will be greater than the c27% implied by assuming a lognormal distribution with a constant volatility assumption equal to the at-the-money option’s implied volatility. Mathematical techniques have been developed to derive the probability distribution implied by volatility smiles such as the one above, and we develop an example below.

 By fitting an exponential curve to the volatility smile, and applying the Breeden and Litzenberger (1978) result2, we obtain a risk-neutral probability distribution for the change in FTSE100 value that is implied by the collection of FTSE 100 option prices. We can then apply a utility function to the risk-neutral probability distribution calibrated to produce an equity risk premium of 4% to capture risk aversion. This has the effect of transforming the risk-neutral probability distribution into a real-world probability distribution.

 Below we show two probability distributions – a lognormal distribution that only considers one option price (the at-the-money option); and the distribution that is implied by the whole set of option prices.

 

 Allowing for the volatility smile and the higher implied volatilities at lower strike prices gives the resulting distribution a fatter left tail than a lognormal distribution. The next table tabulates the impact at key extreme percentiles.

 

 We note that the loss implied by the full set of option prices is consistent with the c43.3% 99.5th percentile loss assumed in the Standard Formula Type 1 equity capital calculation as at 30 June 2025.

 Application to interest rates
 Interest rate options – such as options on interest rate swaps (swaptions) can be used to develop an analogous approach for the estimation of interest rate probability distributions. The chart below shows the volatility smile implied by some 18-month options on the 10-year swap rate, for a range of strike rates.

 The volatility smile looks very different to what we observed for the FTSE100 above.

 

 In this example, we have fitted a clamped cubic spline to these volatilities, instead of the exponential function used in the FTSE100 example. Furthermore, we have assumed the interest rate risk premium is zero, and so there is no difference between the real-world and risk-neutral probability distributions in this example.

 Below we show two probability distributions – a normal distribution that only considers one option price (the at-the-money option); and the distribution that is implied by the whole set of option prices.

 

 As in the FTSE 100 example, allowing for the volatility smile enriches the resulting option-implied distribution. In this example both tails are fatter than the normal distribution. The next table tabulates the impact at key extreme percentiles.

 
 At 30 June 2025, the standard formula interest rate down stress for the 10 year spot rate was a decrease of 1.25%. The standard formula stress is calibrated over a one year period, whereas our analysis on swaptions is over 18 months. Scaling the standard formula stress by √1.5 gives an estimate of the decrease in the 10 year spot rate over 18 months as 1.22%. This is much smaller than the figures implied by swaption prices.

 Conclusions and acknowledging the limitations
 Of course, option-implied distributions aren't perfect. Several factors influence option prices beyond the market’s view of the probability distributions of future outcomes. Perhaps most importantly, we have not allowed for the ways that transaction costs and the presence of unhedgeable risks may impact on option prices. The latter of these is particularly difficult to allow for. For example, if the underlying asset of an option can behave in ways that mean the option exposure cannot be hedged – for example, by making large discontinuous price jumps – then the arbitrage-free option pricing mathematics is compromised.

 It might be argued that option-implied volatilities are upwardly-biased by the absence of allowance for these factors in option pricing models. To make some allowance for this, option-implied volatilities could be scaled down before using them as inputs for deriving implied distributions.

 Nonetheless, we consider that option pricing dynamics, and how they evolve over time, can provide useful forward-looking insights for risk managers. For example, while in the first example above, the implied volatility from a one-year ATM FTSE 100 call option as at 30 June 2025 was c14%, in the last decade it has ranged from c9% to c30%! In an actuarial risk world that is often focused on decades-old data, changes in option prices can act as one of the ‘canaries in the coalmine’ that risk managers can reference to understand real-time changes in the risk environment.

 Endnotes
 1 The log return is calculated as number of standard deviations of the standard normal distribution to reach the 99.5th percentile multiplied by the implied volatility plus the equity risk premium (-2.57 × 14% + 4% = -32%). The equity return is the exponent of the log return.

 2 Breeden and Litzenberger (1978), “Prices of State Contingent Claims Implicit in Option Prices”, Journal of Business, 51, pp621-651. 

Back to Index


Similar News to this Story

The role of insurance in advancing nuclear energy
As the world accelerates its transition to low-carbon energy, nuclear power stands out as a reliable, carbon-free solution. Its ability to provide c
What option prices reveal about future financial risk
Insurance companies are experts at using historical data to form views on possible future outcomes. These views are then used in a variety of ways fro
Retirement and what no one prepares you for
“This is an un-monitored email address”. This is just one of the brick walls I hit as I was trying to get my finances sorted for my retirement. I’ve s

Site Search

Exact   Any  

Latest Actuarial Jobs

Actuarial Login

Email
Password
 Jobseeker    Client
Reminder Logon

APA Sponsors

Actuarial Jobs & News Feeds

Jobs RSS News RSS

WikiActuary

Be the first to contribute to our definitive actuarial reference forum. Built by actuaries for actuaries.