Articles - An Actuarial perspective on Student Loans


This is not a political piece. This is not a polemic, or a campaign for change. This is merely factual analysis of the student loan system from an actuarial and investment perspective, rather than from a moral or governmental one. For those like me who were lucky enough to have studied before the new system, and may not know it, the new student loan system allows £9,250 per annum for tuition fees and a variable maintenance loan.

 By Alex White, Head of ALM Research, Redington

 For students living away from home and studying outside London, this is capped at £8,700. Interest is charged at RPI plus a spread which rises with income up to 3%, and payments are taken as 9% of the portion of salary above a threshold (currently 25,725). Loans are written off after 30 years. The thresholds rise at RPI + 1.6% each year.

 Looking at the structure, there is a lot about it that is well designed, and the goals of the design are fairly clear. Payment amounts are means-based, so low earners are not forced to make huge payments, and no-one pays more than they can afford. The interest charged is also means-tested, which implies a desire not to charge punitive interest to low earners. But does it work?

 As often in finance, the question comes down to what might be an appropriate discount rate. There’s not an obvious choice, but we could start with 95% LTV mortgage rates, on the grounds that this will be a similar demographic. At around 2.5% fixed, these are roughly gilts + 1.5%. This is secured lending to the richer end of the market, so would be a lower bound. Broad market BBB-BB spreads are around 80, so we may want to add that. We would also want to factor in the complex optionality within the payment structure, so we might say gilts plus 3% is a vaguely sensible rate in the current market.

 So what happens? For different salaries, I assumed increases of RPI + 1.6%, in line with the long-term rate used to increase the salary thresholds. I then made some simplifications around payment timings, and projected the loan of a graduate starting now, having just completed a 3y course, and earning different amounts, and worked out the PV of their total payments. In all cases there are no overpayments. While many of these are unlikely to be graduate salaries, the same effect will occur if salaries reach these levels a few years into graduates’ careers. The results are below.

 
 PV of payments on Gilts + 3% (total undiscounted payments)

 
  

 What we see is a slightly bizarre effect. Anyone earning below the threshold pays nothing, and lower earners benefit greatly from this floor. Very high earners can afford to pay off the loan faster than it accrues interest. Those in the middle, however, can expect to make large payments of several thousand pounds per year, while seeing their loan grow faster than they can pay it off. This means they end up paying a lot more than higher earners- the middle does get squeezed. Regardless of political views, it’s unlikely that this was an intentional aspect of the design
 

 

Back to Index


Similar News to this Story

The reserving actuary natural vs artificial intelligence
Why human actuaries still have the upper hand over AI when it comes to the nuanced art of reserving in the insurance industry. Every year, we take in
Five step approach vital for DB schemes looking to buyout
Insurers may refuse to quote and provide pricing for buy-ins and buy-outs where the DB pension schemes’ data is of a poor quality, warns Hymans Robert
What insurers must know about the hidden risks of silent AI
Anja Vischer, Senior Emerging Risk Manager at Swiss Re Institute, discusses the emerging risks of AI for insurers. She stresses the need to reassess c

Site Search

Exact   Any  

Latest Actuarial Jobs

Actuarial Login

Email
Password
 Jobseeker    Client
Reminder Logon

APA Sponsors

Actuarial Jobs & News Feeds

Jobs RSS News RSS

WikiActuary

Be the first to contribute to our definitive actuarial reference forum. Built by actuaries for actuaries.