Articles - It might sound crazy but it aint no lie we need LDI


In the fallout from the gilt crisis in September 2022, there’s been a lot of focus on LDI, and leveraged LDI in particular. Redington has expressed views on this (for instance here*) and this piece aims to complement those views with an alternative perspective on why LDI makes sense. Why do pension schemes do LDI in the first place?

 By Alex White, Head of ALM Research at Redington
 
 Corporate pension schemes are a set of promises from a corporate sponsor to pay pensions (other schemes, such as LGPS schemes, are in a fundamentally different position given the nature of their sponsors, so tend to use different solutions). A pension, at heart, is a stream of income. A typical DB pension is an amount of money known in advance that increases with inflation each year – they look a lot like bonds. The scheme has a pot of money to pay these pensions – failing this, it must rely on contributions from the sponsoring company. This is always a burden on the company to some degree, and in some cases, a crushing one (e.g. Kodak). So schemes try to invest to ensure they can pay pensions without undue reliance on the sponsor.

 Critically, pension schemes aren’t in the business of buying the highest-returning assets for their own sake. They are investing towards a clear goal, and trying to make achieving that goal as likely as possible.

 What if pensions paid gold?
 Suppose a scheme didn’t pay a pension, but instead paid a block of gold on retirement. They would have different problems. There are plenty of portfolios the scheme could hold which could work. For example, equities have generally outperformed gold, so this scheme could hold equities and aim to sell them and buy gold as members retire. However, they would clearly run a lot of risk against the price of gold spiking, which often happens when equities fall. So in an equity crash, the scheme could suddenly find itself in trouble.

 If this scheme had enough money, it could just buy gold (or gold futures) and use it to pay members. That would be ideal - but may not be affordable. If a scheme could afford to buy 99% of the gold it needed, it might hold plenty of gold and a small amount in equities to make up the deficit. We might expect the scheme to hold more gold as the funding position improves.

 Even if the scheme needed a lot more money, we might expect them to take some exposure to the gold price. The biggest risk for this scheme would be gold becoming more expensive, so buying gold futures would reduce the risk and make it more likely that the growth assets could earn enough – in a sense, it would be fixing the goalposts.

 Now suppose the price of gold fell 50%. This scheme would lose 50% of the value of its assets. That sounds terrible – but it would also only need half as much to pay its members. So it would be fine. For this scheme, it would be best to use the asset value divided by the price of gold required to pay members (the funding level) as a barometer of health rather than the asset value alone.

 Linking it back
 If your liabilities are based on gold prices, LDI would advocate you buy gold. DB scheme liabilities are income streams, so LDI implies buying income streams – i.e. bonds. ‘Locking in’ the price of income streams narrows the range of likely outcomes and generally makes it more likely that a scheme can meet its pension payments – and that, if it misses them, it misses them by less.

 From a different angle
 Reversing the problem, we can also ask how difficult it is to pay pensions. If gilt rates are 4%, earning 4% is easy – you buy gilts. If gilt rates are 0%, earning 4% is hard. Fundamentally, you need less money to pay the same pensions with the same degree of certainty when rates are high than when they’re low. So, in a world in which you want a high degree of certainty for the benefit of members, it makes sense for pensions to be valued against interest rates.

 In conclusion
 There are legitimate questions to ask about leverage and collateral management within LDI. The industry has roughly doubled the safety margins typically held, but there are always important details to clarify. That does not mean abandoning the whole edifice of LDI, which exists for very real reasons unrelated to ‘artificial’ accounting.

 As a final point on policy, pension schemes are material buyers of government bonds. Rewriting legislation to discourage them from holding gilts could cause a far larger and faster sell-off, and a greater systemic shock, than the crisis experienced in late 2022.

 * https://redington.co.uk/our-thoughts-on-the-house-of-lords-ldi-letter/ 

Back to Index


Similar News to this Story

September 2024 Edition of the Actuarial Post Magazine
Our cover story comes from Jon Jacobson from Omnisient who looks at applications of Privacy-Preserving Data Collaboration (PPDC) for actuaries. We als
Make your nominations now for the 2024 Actuarial Post Awards
We are pleased to announce that the nominations for the Actuarial Post Awards 2024 are now open! This will be the 12th year of running the awards and
Stars of the Future 2024 Nominate Now
You can now nominate someone for Stars of the Future 2024, sponsored by Star Actuarial Futures. It’s vital to remember that we all started somewhere a

Site Search

Exact   Any  

Latest Actuarial Jobs

Actuarial Login

Email
Password
 Jobseeker    Client
Reminder Logon

APA Sponsors

Actuarial Jobs & News Feeds

Jobs RSS News RSS

WikiActuary

Be the first to contribute to our definitive actuarial reference forum. Built by actuaries for actuaries.